*This is a translation of an article by Yoichi TAKAHASHI,
PPPC Chairman / Kaetsu University Professor,
written for Gendai Business website on September 9, 2013
Tokyo won the right to host the 2020 Olympics. The news made many
Japanese simply happy in the early Sunday morning. The efforts made by
all concerned, including Prime Minister Abe and Tokyo governor Inose,
may deserve admirations, I think.
Abe said “given the decision today, I want to overcome the
deflation-oriented economy lasting for 15 years” and Inose also vowed
to “break away from deflation of the mind”.
Then, let me first summarize the economic impacts of the Olympics.
The ripple effect released by the Tokyo metropolitan government sets
Tokyo and the neighboring areas during 2013-2020 as analytical targets.
It indicates that the induced products would amount to 2,960.9 billion
yen (1,675.3 billion yen in Tokyo, 1,285.6 billion yen in other areas).
The figure was calculated through Tokyo’s original chart on the
inter-industrial effects. Its initial breakdown accounts 1,223.9
billion (Tokyo 966.9 bn., others 2.57 bn.) yen for the construction of
the Olympics related facilities, operational costs, accommodation and
food/drink by visitors. And as its first ripple effect the calculation
accounts additional 1.1 trillion yen premised on a special procurement
boom. Further, as its second ripple effect, it adds 600 bn. yen for
expanded consumptions by the laborers in the Olympics-related
industries. So finally the total sum of induced products will amount
to 2,960.9 bn. yen, the trial calculation by Tokyo seems to be saying.
<Tokyo Olympics with the existing facilities is a paying business>
Besides 2,960.9 bn. yen of the induced
products, Tokyo’s calculation
entails 1,421 bn. yen of induced
added-values (Tokyo 858.6 bn., others
5.624 bn.) and 755.3 bn. yen of induced
income for employees (Tokyo
468.7 bn., others 284.6 bn.) separately.
Using the trial calculation by Tokyo, one
construction company stated
in its website that the ripple economic
effect of the Olympics will
amount to 5.135 trillion yen in total; a
simple sum of those figures.
But the number is not right. To note,
the induced products may entail
overlapping accounts as it focuses on
the product-base alone. Also,
while the induced added-value refers to
the profits, the induced
income for employees means the salaries
of employees within the
profits. So, there is likely a threefold
overlapping accounting in the
calculation.
Anyways, Tokyo metropolitan government also
predicts that the
Olympics will induce 152,202 employments
(Tokyo 83,706, others 68,496).
Aside from these ripple economic effects, by
simply looking at the
earnings and expenses of the Olympics
since Los Angeles in 1984,
Olympics is no doubt a profit-making,
commercial event.
The main sources of earnings in the Olympics
are (1) broadcasting
rights, (2) payments by sponsors, (3)
admission fees (gate money), and
(4) sales of commemorative goods. In
Tokyo, like in London, the
running costs can be kept low for the
many existing facilities
avoiding additional construction costs
for new stadiums, etc., and the
account will likely get into the black
without much budgetary spending.
In any respect, the Olympics, moving the
people’s feelings for two
weeks, is surely one of the fewest, most
promising business projects
in the modern world.
<Cool views on the economic effects
by economists>
Quite a few economists have rather critical
views on such the trial
calculations. Yes, indeed, such trial
calculations usually have
certain assumptions which always accompany
risks of being questioned
on their neutrality and rationality. But
some critics seem to be
rather excessive on this point.
First, some say that Tokyo’s calculation is based on a “partial
equilibrium” assumption that the other conditions are prefixed. For
that reason, such calculations do not
take into consideration the
consumption and investment decreased due
to the increased consumption
and investment by the Olympics, they
would say. Such a criticism is
not off the point at all, indeed. For
instance, it is like saying that
an expansion of public works projects in
Tokyo would hinder the
reconstruction works in the
quake-stricken areas because it mobilizes
labors even from the suffered Tohoku
region. This sort of criticism
deserves a careful consideration, of
course. Nevertheless, as it is to
be mentioned later, such
counterarguments are rather of a minor kind
compared to the political aspect of
hosting and preparing the Olympics.
Another counterargument is such that while the
hosting cities had
invested huge amount of money to
construct the related facilities, the
same facilities and buildings would
never be used in the future. But
it doesn’t apply to Tokyo because Tokyo already has lots of existing
facilities and will be able to respond
adequately just by simply
repairing them.
There are yet other negative voices against
the rushing demands for
construction and guarding expenses
toward opening of the Games. But I
don’t think the 2020 Tokyo Olympics costs a lot more than in other
cities.
<Exports will increase by 30
percent>
Although it is generally the nature of
economists to point out minor
points, there are the economists who
speak of the noteworthy points
from a grand perspective. I remind of “The Olympic Effect”
co-authored by Andrew Rose and Mark
Spiegel.
According to the authors, the countries which
hosted the Olympics
during 1950-2006 increased the
international trades by 30% in average
mainly due to the free-trade and
deregulatory measures simultaneously
undertaken with the Olympic Games. In
short, it is to say that the
liberalization measures by the hosting
countries to make themselves
look good actually contributed to their
own economic growth as the
result.
The interesting point about the literature is
the perspective that
the external, internationally-political
aspect of the deregulatory
measures had a greater economic effect
than the internal,
domestically-political aspect of the
public works projects for opening
the Olympics.
An application of this lesson to Japan today
would be the TPP and
“deregulation”, the third arrow of the Abenomics. While the TPP
might bring short-term disadvantages to
Japan, liberalization and
deregulation of the country’s markets will surely lead to a long-term
economic growth, as well as that some
surprising experiments will
seemingly bring about further national
interests.
<Ideas such as Casino and 24
hours-transportations>
Tokyo governor Inose is the figure having
insisted to establish and
legalize Casino in bayside Odaiba, and
also who already partially
realized the 24 hours-running of the
Tokyo metropolitan transportation
via internationalization of the Haneda
Airport. I’m sure the governor
Inose should come up with many ideas to
select some Tokyo areas for
experimental deregulatory measures to
realize forefront cities, and
the Abe Cabinet may simply approve them
as the so-called Abenomics
Special Zones to advance the regulatory
reforms even temporarily and
locally under the nominal aim of the
Olympics.
This is not a privilege to Tokyo. The Abe
Cabinet is inviting any
ideas and proposals on the National
Strategic Special Zones with local
originalities. As the primary aim of the
government’s Council on
Industrial Competitiveness this time is
the regulatory reform itself,
it is hard to imagine that an
excessively-deregulatory proposition
would be rejected as it was actually the
case under DPJ government’s
Comprehensive Special Zones.
From my own experience as a government
official, any regulative
reforms are demanding both in terms of
times and energies, consuming
3-5 years from policy-planning, enacting
processes to actually feeling
the policy consequences. This is to say
that the seven-years-ahead
Olympics is apt for experimenting such
long-term deregulatory measures.
While it would be odd to speak of an “if…” story, I still
believe
that a combination of the Olympics, the TPP,
and the Abenomics Special
Zones may enable a long-term economic
reflation until 2020.
The Cabinet Office released that the economy
had been in the
recovering phase for the 37 straight
months since March 2009 till
April 2013. It means that March 2009 was
the “bottom” and April 2013
was the “top”. Though the economic
figures are not released
officially yet, November 2012 will
likely be another “bottom” and
this will be a good news for the Abe
Cabinet as it would mean that the
Cabinet experienced the second shortest
7 months of economic recession
compared to 16 months of the historical
Cabinets in average.
If November 2012 was really a “bottom” of the economy,
there is a
possibility of experiencing the record
longest 8 years of economic
reflation in the postwar Japan if Tokyo
Olympics is appropriately and
successfully combined with the TPP and
Abenomics Special Zones.