Public Policy Planning & Consulting Co. (SEISAKU-KOUBOU) is a public policy consulting firm based in Tokyo, covering broad policy areas such as economic policy, fiscal policy, regulatory policy, administrative reform, international trade and investment, etc.
PPPC provides consulting and briefing services to the clients in the central/local governments, Diet, local assemblies and the private sector.

This blog is aimed at providing general information, latest updates and some of our analytical reports about Japan's public policy in English.
The contents include;
- updates on some important government councils, especially those in which our executive officers serve as the members,
- weekly reports on latest news in Nagata-cho, the political center in Japan, (partially).
- analytical reports and articles by our members and distinguished experts outside the firm,(partially).

9.17.2013

Olympics to Bring Economic Reflation until 2020? : TPP and SpecialZones are the Keys.


*This is a translation of an article by Yoichi TAKAHASHI,
  PPPC Chairman / Kaetsu University Professor,
  written for Gendai Business website on September 9, 2013


 Tokyo won the right to host the 2020 Olympics. The news made many
Japanese simply happy in the early Sunday morning. The efforts made by
all concerned, including Prime Minister Abe and Tokyo governor Inose,
may deserve admirations, I think.

 Abe said “given the decision today, I want to overcome the
deflation-oriented economy lasting for 15 years” and Inose also vowed
to “break away from deflation of the mind”.

 Then, let me first summarize the economic impacts of the Olympics.

 The ripple effect released by the Tokyo metropolitan government sets
Tokyo and the neighboring areas during 2013-2020 as analytical targets.
It indicates that the induced products would amount to 2,960.9 billion
yen (1,675.3 billion yen in Tokyo, 1,285.6 billion yen in other areas).

 The figure was calculated through Tokyo’s original chart on the
inter-industrial effects. Its initial breakdown accounts 1,223.9
billion (Tokyo 966.9 bn., others 2.57 bn.) yen for the construction of
the Olympics related facilities, operational costs, accommodation and
food/drink by visitors. And as its first ripple effect the calculation
accounts additional 1.1 trillion yen premised on a special procurement
boom. Further, as its second ripple effect, it adds 600 bn. yen for
expanded consumptions by the laborers in the Olympics-related
industries. So finally the total sum of induced products will amount
to 2,960.9 bn. yen, the trial calculation by Tokyo seems to be saying.


<Tokyo Olympics with the existing facilities is a paying business>

 Besides 2,960.9 bn. yen of the induced products, Tokyos calculation
entails 1,421 bn. yen of induced added-values (Tokyo 858.6 bn., others
5.624 bn.) and 755.3 bn. yen of induced income for employees (Tokyo
468.7 bn., others 284.6 bn.) separately.

 Using the trial calculation by Tokyo, one construction company stated
in its website that the ripple economic effect of the Olympics will
amount to 5.135 trillion yen in total; a simple sum of those figures.
But the number is not right. To note, the induced products may entail
overlapping accounts as it focuses on the product-base alone. Also,
while the induced added-value refers to the profits, the induced
income for employees means the salaries of employees within the
profits. So, there is likely a threefold overlapping accounting in the
calculation.

 Anyways, Tokyo metropolitan government also predicts that the
Olympics will induce 152,202 employments (Tokyo 83,706, others 68,496).

 Aside from these ripple economic effects, by simply looking at the
earnings and expenses of the Olympics since Los Angeles in 1984,
Olympics is no doubt a profit-making, commercial event.

 The main sources of earnings in the Olympics are (1) broadcasting
rights, (2) payments by sponsors, (3) admission fees (gate money), and
(4) sales of commemorative goods. In Tokyo, like in London, the
running costs can be kept low for the many existing facilities
avoiding additional construction costs for new stadiums, etc., and the
account will likely get into the black without much budgetary spending.
In any respect, the Olympics, moving the peoples feelings for two
weeks, is surely one of the fewest, most promising business projects
in the modern world.


<Cool views on the economic effects by economists>

 Quite a few economists have rather critical views on such the trial
calculations. Yes, indeed, such trial calculations usually have
certain assumptions which always accompany risks of being questioned
on their neutrality and rationality. But some critics seem to be
rather excessive on this point.

 First, some say that Tokyos calculation is based on a partial
equilibrium assumption that the other conditions are prefixed. For
that reason, such calculations do not take into consideration the
consumption and investment decreased due to the increased consumption
and investment by the Olympics, they would say. Such a criticism is
not off the point at all, indeed. For instance, it is like saying that
an expansion of public works projects in Tokyo would hinder the
reconstruction works in the quake-stricken areas because it mobilizes
labors even from the suffered Tohoku region. This sort of criticism
deserves a careful consideration, of course. Nevertheless, as it is to
be mentioned later, such counterarguments are rather of a minor kind
compared to the political aspect of hosting and preparing the Olympics.

 Another counterargument is such that while the hosting cities had
invested huge amount of money to construct the related facilities, the
same facilities and buildings would never be used in the future. But
it doesnt apply to Tokyo because Tokyo already has lots of existing
facilities and will be able to respond adequately just by simply
repairing them.

 There are yet other negative voices against the rushing demands for
construction and guarding expenses toward opening of the Games. But I
dont think the 2020 Tokyo Olympics costs a lot more than in other
cities.


<Exports will increase by 30 percent>

 Although it is generally the nature of economists to point out minor
points, there are the economists who speak of the noteworthy points
from a grand perspective. I remind of The Olympic Effect
co-authored by Andrew Rose and Mark Spiegel.

 According to the authors, the countries which hosted the Olympics
during 1950-2006 increased the international trades by 30% in average
mainly due to the free-trade and deregulatory measures simultaneously
undertaken with the Olympic Games. In short, it is to say that the
liberalization measures by the hosting countries to make themselves
look good actually contributed to their own economic growth as the
result.

 The interesting point about the literature is the perspective that
the external, internationally-political aspect of the deregulatory
measures had a greater economic effect than the internal,
domestically-political aspect of the public works projects for opening
the Olympics.

 An application of this lesson to Japan today would be the TPP and
deregulation, the third arrow of the Abenomics. While the TPP
might bring short-term disadvantages to Japan, liberalization and
deregulation of the countrys markets will surely lead to a long-term
economic growth, as well as that some surprising experiments will
seemingly bring about further national interests.


<Ideas such as Casino and 24 hours-transportations>

 Tokyo governor Inose is the figure having insisted to establish and
legalize Casino in bayside Odaiba, and also who already partially
realized the 24 hours-running of the Tokyo metropolitan transportation
via internationalization of the Haneda Airport. Im sure the governor
Inose should come up with many ideas to select some Tokyo areas for
experimental deregulatory measures to realize forefront cities, and
the Abe Cabinet may simply approve them as the so-called Abenomics
Special Zones to advance the regulatory reforms even temporarily and
locally under the nominal aim of the Olympics.

 This is not a privilege to Tokyo. The Abe Cabinet is inviting any
ideas and proposals on the National Strategic Special Zones with local
originalities. As the primary aim of the governments Council on
Industrial Competitiveness this time is the regulatory reform itself,
it is hard to imagine that an excessively-deregulatory proposition
would be rejected as it was actually the case under DPJ governments
Comprehensive Special Zones.

 From my own experience as a government official, any regulative
reforms are demanding both in terms of times and energies, consuming
3-5 years from policy-planning, enacting processes to actually feeling
the policy consequences. This is to say that the seven-years-ahead
Olympics is apt for experimenting such long-term deregulatory measures.
While it would be odd to speak of an if…” story, I still believe
that a combination of the Olympics, the TPP, and the Abenomics Special
Zones may enable a long-term economic reflation until 2020.

 The Cabinet Office released that the economy had been in the
recovering phase for the 37 straight months since March 2009 till
April 2013. It means that March 2009 was the bottom and April 2013
was the top. Though the economic figures are not released
officially yet, November 2012 will likely be another bottom and
this will be a good news for the Abe Cabinet as it would mean that the
Cabinet experienced the second shortest 7 months of economic recession
compared to 16 months of the historical Cabinets in average.

 If November 2012 was really a bottom of the economy, there is a
possibility of experiencing the record longest 8 years of economic
reflation in the postwar Japan if Tokyo Olympics is appropriately and
successfully combined with the TPP and Abenomics Special Zones.


No comments:

Post a Comment